Are Current Proposals for a UK Citizen's Wealth Fund Effective in Tackling Economic Inequality?
A policy paper published by think-tank the Institute for Public Policy Research has proposed that all UK born citizens should be given £10000 when they reach the age of 25 to address growing wealth inequality. The study and its subsequent policy recommendations were inspired by startling economic inequality statistics published in the most recent wealth and assets survey carried out by the Office for National Statistics (ONS). The wealthiest 10th of UK households own 44% of the nation’s wealth, whilst 50% of the least wealthy households own just 9% of the nation’s total wealth. The paper develops a working model for tackling endemic economic inequalities via wealth redistribution by establishing a Citizen’s Wealth Fund owned by and run in the interests of citizens which would pay a one-off capital dividend to 25 year olds to invest in their futures, sourcing the money for this handout from a mixture of tax reforms and selling off various assets such as the government’s £24 billion stake in the Royal Bank of Scotland.
A lump sum of £10000 at 25 provides the opportunity for young people to invest in their futures through helping to scale the property ladder (home ownership among 25-34 year olds fell from 59% in 2003 to 37% in 2015), investing in further education or starting their own business. But is giving a handout to all 25 year olds the most useful policy of wealth redistribution in 2018? Is giving £10000 to me at 25 (in 5 and a half years time), a middle class, university educated, privileged white male who will never experience gender wage inequality simply due to the fact that he was born a man, going to be effective in counteracting wealth and income inequalities?
With the acute public funding crisis in the UK, perhaps the policy should stipulate that monies accumulated by the fund should be channelled in ways which help to challenge inequality more indirectly, but on a more societal level, for the Citizen’s Wealth Fund has the potential to become a fighting fund to challenge gender wage inequalities by contributing to child-care costs for working mothers, to save our NHS from a crippling funding crisis and improve our primary and secondary level education with better funding and afford economic assistance to socio-economically disadvantaged further education students who struggle to meet additional university costs stretching beyond their student loans.
The IPPR’s proposal aligns too closely to the Alaskan model, the Alaskan Permanent Fund; under which Alaskan citizen’s receive an annual dividend at $1560 per year on average. Although the proposed UK Citizen’s Wealth Fund pays a lump sum at 25 rather than annually, the policy proposals draw heavily on this idea of a lump sum paid out to all citizens, which I would contend is the wrong route to take. I envisage the UK Citizen’s Wealth Fund being akin to the Australian model, Australia’s Future Fund, funded in the main by investment returns made using the proceeds from the sale of the government’s holding of telecommunications giant Telstra. Australia’s Future Fund has three umbrella strands which instead of paying out a lump sum, tackle wealth inequality more indirectly, focusing on the poorer and more socio-economically disadvantaged strata in society.
The Disability Australia Fund finances Australia’s National Disability Insurance Scheme to support Australians with significant and permanent disabilities and their carers, the Medical Research Future Fund provides grants of financial assistance to support medical research and medical innovation to improve healthcare, whilst the Nation-building Funds invest in educational infrastructure in socio-economically deprived areas.
The IPPR’s Citizen’s Wealth Fund proposal also states that a £10000 dividend should also be paid to 25 year old citizens born outside the UK who have held UK citizenship ‘for a number of years, eligibility specifically based on whether the individual was a UK citizen at the end of secondary education at 16.’ Although I harbour no political opposition to this clause, I fear that right-wing populists in the UK will seize on this proposed policy clause, propagating rhetoric that the ethnic and socio-economic group of “others”, economic migrants and asylum seekers, are not only applying for UK citizenship to put a strain on our public services and welfare benefits system, but also want to gain UK citizenship for their children before 16 so that they are eligible for a £10000 Citizen’s Welfare Fund dividend at 25.
This would appeal to both the working class losers of globalisation who feel they have lost their predominantly manual labour jobs due to outsourcing and cheap migrant labour, which they do not wish to share a universal capital dividend with, and the squeezed middle classes, who fear that their financial and class position is being threatened by parasitic “others” socioeconomically above and below them, both the political and economic “elites” who would introduce the Citizen’s Wealth Fund and the “the others” below them who would primarily capitalise from their contribution to the Fund through taxation reform.
Indeed, this short clause may be the uniting factor that UKIP are looking for to stage a revival in right-wing populist politics, thus to avoid this we must allocate the Citizen’s Welfare Funds to specific crisis’s in public funding in the NHS, education, and welfare benefits.
A Citizen’s Welfare Fund is a bold policy proposal to tackle growing economic inequalities, but we must reject the idea of using the funds to pay out lump sums to all citizens in favour of an overhaul of public service financing to ensure that right wing-populists such as Farage do not capitalise on the xenophobic imagery of an economic migrant or asylum seeker extending their hand across the English Channel for a £10000 dividend.
By Michael McConway